Senin, 23 April 2018

Sponsored Links

Cobb-Douglas Production Function Differentiation Example - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com

In economics and econometrics, the Cobb-Douglas production function is a particular functional form of the production function, widely used to represent the technological relationship between the amounts of two or more inputs (particularly physical capital and labor) and the amount of output that can be produced by those inputs. The Cobb-Douglas form was developed and tested against statistical evidence by Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas during 1927-1947.


Video Cobb-Douglas production function



Formulation

In its most standard form for production of a single good with two factors, the function is

Y = A L ? K ? {\displaystyle Y=AL^{\beta }K^{\alpha }}

where:

  • Y = total production (the real value of all goods produced in a year or 365.25 days)
  • L = labor input (the total number of person-hours worked in a year or 365.25 days)
  • K = capital input (the real value of all machinery, equipment, and buildings) Definition of buildings need clarification. In the context of Capital, buildings include labor. Instead, commodities should be added.
  • A = total factor productivity and your usual depreciation by utility in day after
  • ? and ? are the output elasticities of capital and labor, respectively. These values are constants determined by available technology.

Output elasticity measures the responsiveness of output to a change in levels of either labor or capital used in production, ceteris paribus. For example, if ? = 0.45, a 1% increase in capital usage would lead to approximately a 0.45% increase in output.

Sometimes the term has a more restricted meaning, requiring that the function display constant returns to scale, meaning that doubling the usage of capital K and labor L will also double output Y. This holds if

? + ? = 1,

If

? + ? < 1,

returns to scale are decreasing, and if

? + ? > 1,

returns to scale are increasing. Assuming perfect competition and ? + ? = 1, ? and ? can be shown to be capital's and labor's shares of output.

In its generalized form, the Cobb-Douglas function models more than two goods. The Cobb-Douglas function may be written as:

f ( x ) = A ? i = 1 L x i ? i , x = ( x 1 , ? , x L ) . {\displaystyle f(x)=A\prod _{i=1}^{L}x_{i}^{\lambda _{i}},\qquad x=(x_{1},\cdots ,x_{L}).}

where:

  • A is an efficiency parameter
  • L is the total number of goods
  • x1, ..., xL are the (non-negative) quantities of good consumed, produced, etc.
  • ? i {\displaystyle \lambda _{i}} is an elasticity parameter for good i

Maps Cobb-Douglas production function



History

Paul Douglas explained that his first formulation of the Cobb-Douglas production function was developed in 1927; when seeking a functional form to relate estimates he had calculated for workers and capital, he spoke with mathematician and colleague Charles Cobb, who suggested a function of the form Y = AL?K1-?, previously used by Knut Wicksell. Estimating this using least squares, he obtained a result for the exponent of labour of 0.75--which was subsequently confirmed by the National Bureau of Economic Research to be 0.741. Later work in the 1940s prompted them to allow for the exponents on K and L to vary, resulting in estimates that subsequently proved to be very close to improved measure of productivity developed at that time.

A major criticism at the time was that estimates of the production function, although seemingly accurate, were based on such sparse data that it was hard to give them much credibility. Douglas remarked "I must admit I was discouraged by this criticism and thought of giving up the effort, but there was something which told me I should hold on." The breakthrough came in using US census data, which was cross-sectional and provided a large number of observations. Douglas presented the results of these findings, along with those for other countries, at his 1947 address as president of the American Economic Association. Shortly afterwards, Douglas went into politics and was stricken by ill health--resulting in little further development on his side. However, two decades later, his production function was widely used, being adopted by economists such as Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow. The Cobb-Douglas production function is especially notable for being the first time an aggregate or economy-wide production function had been developed, estimated, and then presented to the profession for analysis; it marked a landmark change in how economists approached macroeconomics from a microeconomics perspective.


Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Production/Utility Functions in 3D
src: www2.hawaii.edu


Difficulties and criticisms

The function has been criticised for its lack of foundation. Cobb and Douglas were influenced by statistical evidence that appeared to show that labor and capital shares of total output were constant over time in developed countries; they explained this by statistical fitting least-squares regression of their production function. There is now doubt over whether constancy over time exists. The Cobb-Douglas production function was not developed on the basis of any knowledge of engineering, technology, or management of the production process. This rationale may be true given the definition of the Capital term. Labor hours and Capital need a better definition. If capital is defined as a building, labor is already included in the development of that building. A building is composed of commodities, labor and risks and general conditions. It was instead developed because it had attractive mathematical characteristics, such as diminishing marginal returns to either factor of production and the property that the optimal expenditure shares on any given input of a firm operating a Cobb Douglas technology are constant. Initially, there were no utility foundations for it. In the modern era, economists try to build models up from individual agents acting, rather than imposing a functional form on an entire economy. The Cobb-Douglas production function, if properly defined, can be applied at a micro-economic level, up to a macro- economic level. However, many modern authors have developed models which give microeconomically based Cobb-Douglas production functions, including many New Keynesian models. It is nevertheless a mathematical mistake to assume that just because the Cobb-Douglas function applies at the microeconomic level, it also always applies at the macroeconomic level. Similarly, it is not necessarily the case that a macro Cobb-Douglas applies at the disaggregated level. An early microfoundation of the aggregate Cobb-Douglas technology based on linear activities is derived in Houthakker (1955).


How to use excel to estimate the Cobb-Douglas Production function ...
src: i.ytimg.com


Cobb-Douglas utilities

The Cobb-Douglas function is often used as a utility function. In this context the consumer is assumed to have finite wealth, and utility maximization takes the form:

max x u ( x ) = max x i ? i = 1 L x i ? i  subject to the constraint  ? i = 1 L p i x i = w {\displaystyle \max _{x}u(x)=\max _{x_{i}}\prod _{i=1}^{L}x_{i}^{\alpha _{i}}\quad {\text{ subject to the constraint }}\quad \sum _{i=1}^{L}p_{i}x_{i}=w}

where w {\displaystyle w} is the total wealth of the consumer and p i {\displaystyle p_{i}} are the prices of the goods. The utility may be maximized as follows. First, take the logarithm of the utility

ln u ( x ) = ? i = 1 L ? i ln x i {\displaystyle \ln u(x)=\sum _{i=1}^{L}{\lambda _{i}}\ln x_{i}}

Let ? = ?1 + ... + ?L. Since the function x ? x 1 ? {\displaystyle x\mapsto x^{\frac {1}{\lambda }}} is strictly monotone for x > 0, it follows that u ( x ) = u ~ ( x ) 1 ? {\displaystyle u(x)={\tilde {u}}(x)^{\frac {1}{\lambda }}} represents the same preferences. Setting ? i = ? i ? {\displaystyle \alpha _{i}={\frac {\lambda _{i}}{\lambda }}} it can be shown that

? i = 1 L ? i = 1 {\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{L}\alpha _{i}=1}

The optimal solution is then:

? j : x j ? = w ? j p j . {\displaystyle \forall j:\qquad x_{j}^{\star }={\frac {w\alpha _{j}}{p_{j}}}.}

An interpretation of this solution is that the consumer uses a fraction ? j {\displaystyle \alpha _{j}} of his wealth in purchasing good j.

The indirect utility function can be calculated by substituting the demand into the utility function. Ignoring a certain multiplicative constant which depends only on the ? i {\displaystyle \alpha _{i}} s, we get:

v ( p , w ) = w ? i = 1 L p i ? i {\displaystyle v(p,w)={\frac {w}{\prod _{i=1}^{L}p_{i}^{\alpha _{i}}}}}

which is a special case of the Gorman polar form. The expenditure function is the inverse of the indirect utility function:

e ( p , u ) = ? i = 1 L p i ? i u {\displaystyle e(p,u)=\prod _{i=1}^{L}p_{i}^{\alpha _{i}}u}

Long Term Economic Growth - ppt download
src: slideplayer.com


Various representations of the production function

The Cobb-Douglas function form can be estimated as a linear relationship using the following expression:

ln ( Y ) = a 0 + ? i a i ln ( I i ) {\displaystyle \ln(Y)=a_{0}+\sum _{i}a_{i}\ln(I_{i})}

Where:

  • Y = Output {\displaystyle Y={\text{Output}}}
  • I i = Inputs {\displaystyle I_{i}={\text{Inputs}}}
  • a i = Model coefficients {\displaystyle a_{i}={\text{Model coefficients}}}

The model can also be written as

Y = ( I 1 ) a 1 ? ( I 2 ) a 2 ? {\displaystyle Y=(I_{1})^{a_{1}}\cdot (I_{2})^{a_{2}}\cdots }

As noted, the common Cobb-Douglas function used in macroeconomic modeling is

Y = K ? L ? {\displaystyle Y=K^{\alpha }L^{\beta }}

where K is capital and L is labor. When the model exponents sum to one, the production function is first-order homogeneous, which implies constant returns to scale--that is, if all inputs are scaled by a common factor greater than zero, output will be scaled by the same factor.


Partial Differentiation Part 4 (Cobb-Douglas Production Functions ...
src: i.ytimg.com


Relationship to the CES production function

The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function (in the two-factor case) is

Y = A ( ? K ? + ( 1 - ? ) L ? ) 1 ? , {\displaystyle Y=A\left(\alpha K^{\gamma }+(1-\alpha )L^{\gamma }\right)^{\frac {1}{\gamma }},}

in which the limiting case ? = 0 corresponds to a Cobb-Douglas function, Y = A K ? L 1 - ? , {\displaystyle Y=AK^{\alpha }L^{1-\alpha },} with constant returns to scale.

To see this, the log of the CES function,

ln ( Y ) = ln ( A ) + 1 ? ln ( ? K ? + ( 1 - ? ) L ? ) {\displaystyle \ln(Y)=\ln(A)+{\frac {1}{\gamma }}\ln \left(\alpha K^{\gamma }+(1-\alpha )L^{\gamma }\right)}

can be taken to the limit by applying l'Hôpital's rule:

lim ? -> 0 ln ( Y ) = ln ( A ) + ? ln ( K ) + ( 1 - ? ) ln ( L ) . {\displaystyle \lim _{\gamma \to 0}\ln(Y)=\ln(A)+\alpha \ln(K)+(1-\alpha )\ln(L).}

Therefore, Y = A K ? L 1 - ? {\displaystyle Y=AK^{\alpha }L^{1-\alpha }} .

Translog production function

The translog production function is an approximation of the CES function by a second-order Taylor polynomial about ? = 0 {\displaystyle \gamma =0} , i.e. the Cobb-Douglas case. The name translog stands for 'transcendental logarithmic'. It is often used in econometrics for the fact that it is linear in the parameters, which means ordinary least squares is applicable.

In the two-factor case above the translog production function is

ln ( Y ) = ln ( A ) + ? ln ( K ) + ( 1 - ? ) ln ( L ) + 1 2 ? ? ( 1 - ? ) [ ln ( K ) - ln ( L ) ] 2 = ln ( A ) + a K ln ( K ) + a L ln ( L ) + b K K ln 2 ( K ) + b L L ln 2 ( L ) + b K L ln ( K ) ln ( L ) {\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}\ln(Y)&=\ln(A)+\alpha \ln(K)+(1-\alpha )\ln(L)+{\frac {1}{2}}\gamma \alpha (1-\alpha )\left[\ln(K)-\ln(L)\right]^{2}\\&=\ln(A)+a_{K}\ln(K)+a_{L}\ln(L)+b_{KK}\ln ^{2}(K)+b_{LL}\ln ^{2}(L)+b_{KL}\ln(K)\ln(L)\end{aligned}}}

where a K {\displaystyle a_{K}} , a L {\displaystyle a_{L}} , b K K {\displaystyle b_{KK}} , b L L {\displaystyle b_{LL}} , and b K L {\displaystyle b_{KL}} are defined appropriately. In the three factor case, the translog production function is:

ln ( Y ) = ln ( A ) + a L ln ( L ) + a K ln ( K ) + a M ln ( M ) + b L L ln 2 ( L ) + b K K ln 2 ( K ) + b M M ln 2 ( M ) + b L K ln ( L ) ln ( K ) + b L M ln ( L ) ln ( M ) + b K M ln ( K ) ln ( M ) = f ( L , K , M ) . {\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}\ln(Y)&=\ln(A)+a_{L}\ln(L)+a_{K}\ln(K)+a_{M}\ln(M)+b_{LL}\ln ^{2}(L)+b_{KK}\ln ^{2}(K)+b_{MM}\ln ^{2}(M)\\&{}\qquad \qquad +b_{LK}\ln(L)\ln(K)+b_{LM}\ln(L)\ln(M)+b_{KM}\ln(K)\ln(M)\\&=f(L,K,M).\end{aligned}}}

where A {\displaystyle A} = total factor productivity, L {\displaystyle L} = labor, K {\displaystyle K} = capital, M {\displaystyle M} = materials and supplies, and Y {\displaystyle Y} = output.


Long Term Economic Growth - ppt download
src: slideplayer.com


See also

  • Leontief production function
  • Production-possibility frontier
  • Production theory

Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Production/Utility Functions in 3D
src: www2.hawaii.edu


References


MRS for Cobb Douglas Utility: The EASY WAY!!! - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com


Further reading

  • Renshaw, Geoff (2005). Maths for Economics. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 516-526. ISBN 0-19-926746-4. 

In this chapter, we learn: - ppt download
src: slideplayer.com


External links

  • Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Type Production Functions in 3D
  • Analysis of the Cobb-Douglas as a utility function
  • Closed Form Solution for a firm with an N-input production function

Source of the article : Wikipedia

Comments
0 Comments